Monday, March 30, 2015

Causes and Effects of Wage Growth

Over here, a huge stack of exams, sitting ungraded since… no, I can't say, it's too embarrassing.  There, a grant proposal that extensive experimentation has shown will not, in fact, write itself. And I still owe a response to all the responses and criticism to my Disgorge the Cash paper for Roosevelt. So naturally, I thought this morning would be a good time to sit down and ask what we can learn from comparing the path of labor costs in the Employment Cost Index compared with the ECEC.

The BLS explains the difference between the two measures:
The Employment Cost Index, or ECI, measures changes in employers’ cost of compensating workers, controlling for changes in the industrial-occupational composition of jobs. … The ECI is intended to indicate how the average compensation paid by employers would have changed over time if the industrial-occupational composition of employment had not changed… [It] controls for employment shifts across 2-digit industries and major occupations. The Employer Costs for Employee Compensation, or ECEC… is designed to measure the average cost of employee compensation. Accordingly, the ECEC is calculated by multiplying each job quote by its sample weight.
In other words, the ECI measures the change in average hourly compensation, controlling for shifts in the mix of industries and occupations. The ECEC simply measures the overall change in hourly compensation, including the effects of both changes in compensation for particular jobs, and changes in the mix of jobs.

Here are the two series for the full period both are available (1987-2014), both raw and adjusted for inflation ("real").



What do we learn from this?

First, the two series are closely correlated. This tells us that most of the variation in compensation is driven by changes within occupations and sectors, not by shifts in employment between occupations and sectors. This is clearly true at annual frequencies but it seems to be true over longer periods as well. For instance, let's compare the behavior of compensation in the five years since the end of the recession to the last period of strong wage growth, 1997-2004. The difference between the two periods in the average annual increase in nominal wages is almost exactly the same according to the two indexes — 2.7 points by the ECI, 2.6 points by the ECEC. In other words, slower wage growth in the recent period is entirely due to slower wages growth within particular kinds of jobs. Shifts in the composition of jobs have played no role at all.

On the face of it, the fact that almost all variation in aggregate compensation is driven by changes within employment categories, seems to favor a labor/political story of slower wage growth as opposed to a China or robots story. The most obvious versions of the latter two stories involve a disproportionate loss of high-wage jobs, whereas stories about weaker bargaining position of labor predict slower compensation growth within job categories. I wouldn't ask this one piece of evidence to carry a lot of weight in that debate. (I think it's stronger evidence against a skills-based explanation of slower wage growth.)

While the two series in general move together, the ECEC is more strongly cyclical. In other words, during periods of high unemployment and falling wages in general, there is also a shift in the composition of employment towards lower-paid occupations. And during booms, when unemployment is low and wages are rising in general, there is a shift in the direction of higher-paid job categories. [1] Insofar as wages and labor productivity are correlated, this cyclical shift between higher-wage and lower-wage sectors could help explain why employment is more stable than output. I've had the idea for a while that the Okun's law relationship -- the less than one-for-one correlation between employment and output growth -- reflects not only hiring/firing costs and overhead labor, but also shifts in the composition of employment in response to demand. In other words, in addition to employment adjustment costs at the level of individual enterprises, the Okun coefficient reflects cyclically varying degrees of "disguised unemployment" in Joan Robinson's sense. [2] This is an argument I'd like to develop properly someday, since it seems fairly obvious, potentially important and empirically tractable, and I haven't seen anyone else make it. [3] (I'm sure someone has.)

What's going on in the most recent year? Evidently, there has been no acceleration of wage growth for a given job, but the mix of jobs created has shifted toward higher-wage categories. This suggests that to the extent wages are rising faster, it's not a sign of labor-market pressures. (Some guy from Deutsche Bank interprets the same divergence as support for raising rates, which it's hard not to feel is deliberately dishonest.) As for which particular higher-wage job categories are growing more rapidly -- I don't know. And, what's going on in 1995? That year has by far the biggest divergence between the two series. It could well be an artifact of some kind, but if not, seems important. A large fall in the ECEC relative to the ECI could be a signature of deindustrialization. I'm not exploring the question further now (those exams…) but it would be interesting to ask analogous question with some series that extends earlier. It's likely that if we were looking at the 1970s-1980s, we would find a much larger share of variation in wage growth explained by compositional shifts.

Should we adjust for inflation? I give the "real" series here, but I am in general skeptical that there is any sense in which an ex post adjustment of money flows for inflation is more real than, say, The Real World on MTV. I am even more doubtful than usual in this case, because we are normally told to think that changes in nominal wages are the main determinant of inflation. Obviously in that case we have to think of the underlying labor-market process as determining a change in nominal wage. Still, if we do compute a "real" index, things look a little different. Real ECI rises 14 percent over the full 1987-2014 period, while real ECEC rises only 5 percent. So now we can say that about two-thirds of the increase in real wages within particular job categories over the past three decades, was offset by a shift in the composition of employment toward lower-paid job categories. (This is all in the first decade, 1987-1996, however.) This way of looking at things makes sense if we think the underlying wage-setting process, whatever it is, operates in terms of a basket of consumption goods.

This invites another question: How true is it that nominal wages move with inflation?

Conventional economics wisdom suggests we can separate wages into nominal and "real" components. This is on two not quite consistent grounds. First, we might suppose that workers and employers are implicitly negotiating contracts in terms of a fixe quantity of labor time for, on the one hand, a basket of wage goods, and on the other, a basket of produced goods (which will be traded for consumption good for the employer). This contract only incidentally happens to be stated in terms of money. The ultimate terms on which consumption goods for the workers exchange with consumption goods for the employer should not be affected by the units the trade happens to be denominated in. (In this respect the labor contract is just like any other contract.) This is the idea behind Milton Friedman's "natural rate of unemployment" hypothesis. In Friedman's story, causality runs strictly from inflation to unemployment. High inflation is not immediately recognized by workers, leading them to overestimate the basket of goods their wages will buy. So they work more hours than they would have chosen if they had correctly understood the situation. From this point of view, there's no cost to low unemployment in itself; the problem is just that unemployment will only be low if high inflation has tricked workers into supply too much labor. Needless to say, this is not the way anyone in the policy world thinks about the inflation-unemployment nexus today, even if they continue to use Friedman's natural rate language.

The alternative view is that workers and employers negotiate a money-wage, and then output prices are set as a markup over that wage. In this story, causality runs from unemployment to inflation. While Friedman thought an appropriate money-supply growth rate was the necessary and sufficient condition for stable prices, with any affect on unemployment just  collateral damage from changes in inflation, in this story keeping unemployment at an appropriate level is a requirement for stabilizing prices. This is the policy orthodoxy today.  (So while people often say that NAIRU is just another name for the natural rate of unemployment, in fact they are different concepts.) I think there are serious conceptual difficulties with the orthodox view, but we'll save those for another time. Suffice it to say that causality is supposed to run from low unemployment, to faster nominal wage growth, to higher inflation. So the question is: Is it really the case that faster nominal wage growth is associated with higher inflation?

Wage Growth and Inflation, 1947-2014


A simple scatterplot suggests a fairly tight relationship, especially at higher levels of wage growth and inflation. But if we split the postwar period at 1985, things look very different. In the first period, there's a close relationship — regressing inflation on nominal wage growth gives an R-squared of 0.81. (Although even then the coefficient is significantly less than 1.)

Wage Growth and Inflation, 1947-1985


Since 1985, though, the relationship is much looser, with an R-squared of 0.12. And even is that driven almost entirely by period of falling wages and prices in 2009; remove that and the correlation is essentially zero.

Wage Growth and Inflation, 1986-2014


So while it was formerly true that changes in inflation were passed one for one into changes in nominal wages, and/or changes in nominal wage growth led to similar changes in inflation, neither of those things has been true for quite a while now. In recent decades, faster nominal wage growth does not translate into higher inflation.

Obviously, a few scatterplots aren't dispositive, but they are suggestive. So supposing that there has been a  delinking of wage growth and inflation, what conclusions might we draw? I can think of a couple.

On the one hand, maybe we shouldn't be so dismissive of  the naive view that inflation reduces the standard of living directly, by raising the costs of consumption goods while incomes are unchanged. There seems to be an emerging conventional wisdom in this vicinity. Here for instance is Gillian Tett in the FT, endorsing the BIS view that there's nothing wrong with falling prices as long as asset prices stay high. (Priorities.) In the view of both Keynes (in the GT; he modified it later) and Schumpeter, inflation was associated with higher nominal but lower real wages, deflation with lower nominal but higher real wages. I think this may have been true in the 19th century. It's not impossible it could be true in the future.

On the other hand. If the mission of central banks is price stability, and if there is no reliable association between changes in wage growth and changes in inflation, then it is hard to see the argument for tightening in response to falling unemployment. You really should wait for direct evidence of rising inflation. Yet central banks are as focused on unemployment as ever.

It's perhaps significant in this regard that the authorities in Europe are shifting away from the NAIRU (Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment) and increasingly talking about the NAWRU (Non-Accelerating Wage Rate of Unemployment). If the goal all along has been lower wage growth, then this is what you should expect: When the link between wages and inflation weakens, the response is not to find other tools for controlling inflation, but other arguments for controlling wages. This may be the real content of the "competitiveness" discourse. Elevating competitiveness over price stability as overarching goal of policy lets you keep pushing down wages even when inflation is already low.

Worth noting here: While the ECB's "surrender Dorothy" letter to the Spanish government ordered them to get rid of price indexing, their justification was not, as you might expect, that indexation contributes to inflationary spirals. Rather it was that it is "a structural obstacle to the adjustment of labour costs" and "contribute to hampering competitiveness." [4]  This is interesting. In the old days we would have said, wage indexing is bad because it won't affect real wages, it just leads to higher inflation. But apparently in the new dispensation, we say that wage indexing is bad precisely because it does affect real wages.




[1]  This might seem to contradict the previous point but it doesn't, it's just that the post-2009 recovery period includes both a negative composition shift in 2008-2009, when unemployment was high, and a positive compositional shift in 2014, which cancel each other out.

[2] From A Theory of Employment: "Except under peculiar conditions, a decline in effective demand which reduces the amount of employment offered in the general run of industries will not lead to 'unemployment' in the sense of complete idleness, but will rather drive workers into a number of occupations [such as] selling match-boxes in the Strand, cutting brushwood in the jungles, digging potatoes on allotments which are still open to them. A decline in one sort of employment leads to an increase in another sort, and at first sight it may appear that, in such a case, a decline in effective demand does not cause unemployment at all. But the matter must be more closely examined. In all those occupations which the dismissed workers take up, their productivity is less than in the occupations that they have left."

[3] The only piece I know of that makes the connection between demand and productivity variation across sectors is this excellent article by John Eatwell (which unfortunately doesn't seem to be available online), but it is focused on long run variation, not cyclical.

[4] The ECB's English is not the most felicitous, is it? The Spanish version is "contribuyen a dificultar la competitividad y el crecimiento," which also doesn't strike me as a phrase that a native speaker would write. Maybe it sounds better in the original German.

115 comments:

  1. The fact that inflation didn't spike hard upwards in the 3-4% unemployment of the late 1990s should have been a big warning that we are in a different era than the prior one.

    I wonder why 1985 was the transition point? Can't remember any particular policy or financial changes from then.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Well, there are two distinct steps here. First is the link between unemployment and wages, and second is the link between wages and inflation. A failure of inflation to accelerate when unemployment falls tells us that one of those links is broken, but not which one.

      Delete
    2. "Can't remember any particular policy or financial changes from then."

      The Plaza accord?

      Delete
  2. 1995 is just after NAFTA came into effect, no?

    ReplyDelete
  3. Going beyond ink-blot association
    Comment on ‘Causes and Effects of Wage Growth’

    It is pretty clear that your post lacks an underlying coherent theory. Looking at data without a well-defined theoretical perspective is not different from reading tea leaves or from freely associating about an ink-blot. Accordingly, the argument consists of a parade of various popular stories (here five in total, i.e. labor/political, China/robot, Friedman, markup, NAIRU).

    Storytelling is the natural mode of communication in political (i.e. proto-scientific) economics. As Hicks once summed up a similar discussion:

    “As far as I can make out, there are relevant and important senses in which all these statements are each of them right and each of them wrong.” (1939, p. 184)

    Inconclusiveness is a convenient stratagem because “... you cannot prove a vague theory wrong.” (Feynman, 1992, p. 158). Exactly for this reason it is methodologically unacceptable

    In order to get out of this medieval angels-on-a-pinpoint discussion a theoretical fix point is needed that satisfies the criteria of material and formal consistency. To make a long argument (2015; 2014; 2012) short, the correct employment equation for the investment economy is given here:

    https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:AXEC46.png

    The equation says that employment L increases with
    • investment expenditures I,
    • an increasing expenditure ratio rhoE (=C/Y),
    • an increasing factor cost ratio rhoF (=W/PR),
    under the condition of product market clearing if price P and productivity R in the consumption and investment good industry as well as distributed profit Yd remain unaltered in the period under consideration. A falling average wage rate for the business sector as a whole increases unemployment.

    The testable structural employment equation is general; it includes the working of the wage-price mechanism and contains Keynes's argument as a special case. Finally, it holds under inflationary and deflationary conditions.

    The testable structural employment equation terminates inconclusive wish-wash and unambiguously determines the relationship of wage rate, price, productivity, aggregate demand, the income distribution, and employment.

    Egmont Kakarot-Handtke

    References
    Feynman, R. P. (1992). The Character of Physical Law. London: Penguin.
    Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 2nd edition.
    Kakarot-Handtke, E. (2012). Keynes’s Employment Function and the Gratuitous
    Phillips Curve Desaster. SSRN Working Paper Series, 2130421: 1–19. URL
    http://ssrn.com/abstract=2130421.
    Kakarot-Handtke, E. (2014). The Three Fatal Mistakes of Yesterday Economics:
    Profit, I=S, Employment. SSRN Working Paper Series, 2489792: 1–13. URL
    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2489792.
    Kakarot-Handtke, E. (2015). Essentials of Constructive Heterodoxy: Employment.
    SSRN Working Paper Series, 2576867: 1–11. URL http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/
    papers.cfm?abstract_id=2576867.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. It seems to me that "angels on a pin" is the opposite of "inkblot storytelling." One describes excessive formalization, the other insufficient formalization. We'd like to find a path between the two extremes -- to move from the concrete to abstract, and then back to the concrete.

      Delete
  4. IMHO, the relevant point here is not real wages, but the wage share.

    Real wages are equal to productivity X wage share. But "productivity" depends on a lot of stuff that doesn't have a direct correlation with economic policies, for example if a lot of oil wells close in Saudi Arabia arguably productivity in the USA will fall, even if this has nothing to do with workers negotiating their wages in nominal terms or high unemployment keeping wages low.

    Thus the relevant correlation would be between the wage share, unemployment, and inflation; in this story unemployment should lead to a lower wage share. We could say that a big reserve army of labour is needed to keep the wage share low.
    PS: Friedman idea that workers negotiate wages in real terms is crazy because, if this was true, real wages would never rise and would be stuck at some fixed level (admittedly this in part happened in the USA but I think that it is a weird situation).

    What happened in 1985? I'm currently reading Varoufakis's Global Minotaur, and it seems that in the late 70's, early 80's the USA shifted from being basically an exporter nation to being basically an importer nation, sustained from the fact that other nations badly want to be net exporters.
    The change in 1985 could be the effect of the regime change of what V. calls the "Global Plan" regime to the "Global Minotaur" regime.
    In this hipothesis, up to the early 80s wages made the larger part of USA effective demand, later USA demand became more capital driven. This change is what you point out in your "Disgorge the cash" paper. Thus in the first period growth in nominal wages constrained growth in nominal prices, while in the second period the disgorged cash adds to aggregate demand, and the price level decouples from the wage level, causing a fall in the wage share.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. "This change is what you point out in your "Disgorge the cash" paper."

      Meaning that in your paper you point out a change in the relationship between management and shareholders in corporations, but this happens more or less at the same point in time that Varoufakis says there is the change between "Global Plan" and "Global Minotaur".

      Delete
  5. About the ECB, the drive for "competitiveness" is different from fiscal consolidation, austerity and the "confidence fairy" but I found this post interesting:

    https://fsaraceno.wordpress.com/2015/03/25/the-confidence-witch/

    "Remember the old times? Here is a quote from ECB President Jean-Claude Trichet, September 2nd, 2010:

    "[Fiscal Consolidation] is a prerequisite for maintaining confidence in the credibility of governments’ fiscal targets. Positive effects on confidence can compensate for the reduction in demand stemming from fiscal consolidation, when fiscal adjustment strategies are perceived as credible, ambitious and focused on the expenditure side. The conditions for such positive effects are particularly favourable in the current environment of macroeconomic uncertainty."

    And just in case it was not clear, on September 3rd, 2010:

    "We encourage all countries to be absolutely determined to go back to a sustainable mode for their fiscal policies,” Trichet said, speaking after the ECB rate decision on Thursday. “Our message is the same for all, and we trust that it is absolutely decisive not only for each country individually, but for prosperity of all.”

    “Not because it is an elementary recommendation to care for your sons and daughter and not overburden them, but because it is good for confidence, consumption and investment today”.

    Well, think again. Here is the abstract of ECB Working Paper no 1770, March 2015:

    "We explore how fiscal consolidations affect private sector confidence, a possible channel for the fiscal transmission that has received particular attention recently as a result of governments embarking on austerity trajectories in the aftermath of the crisis. Panel regressions based on the action-based datasets of De Vries et al. (2011) and Alesina et al. (2014) show that consolidations, and in particular their unanticipated components affect confidence negatively. The effects are stronger for revenue-based measures and when institutional arrangements, such as fiscal rules, are weak. To obtain a more accurate picture of how consolidations affect confidence, we co nstruct a monthly dataset of consolidation announcements based on the aforementioned datasets, so that we can study the confidence effects in real time using an event study. Consumer confidence falls around announcements of consolidation measures, an effect driven by revenue-based measures. Moreover, the effects are most relevant for European countries with weak institutional arrangements, as measured by the tightness of fiscal rules or budgetary transparency. The effects on producer confidence are generally similar, but weaker than for consumer confidence.

    The confidence fairy seems to have turned into a confidence witch. One more victim of the crisis. But this one will not be missed.
    ...."

    Granted its' the ECB's research arm, but still. They seem to be saying austerity doesn't "work" via the confidence fairy. It makes things worse. Wasn't the confidence fairy supposed to compensate for or mitigate the pain of making the export sector more competitive? Or it would help boost growth along with exports? But it hasn't worked in Greece, Spain, etc.

    I'm reading that Europe is actually easing up on the fiscal austerity and so it will make it appear as if QE and the painful work of gaining competitiveness have worked more than they have with a possible recovery in Europe.

    ReplyDelete
  6. About wages, it appears that Yellen herself is backing off the link with inflation if you look at her speech from last Friday:

    http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150327a.htm

    "But the outlook for wages is highly uncertain even if price inflation does move back to 2 percent and labor market conditions continue to improve as projected. For example, we cannot be sure about the future pace of productivity growth; nor can we be sure about other factors, such as global competition, the nature of technological change, and trends in unionization, that may also influence the pace of real wage growth over time. These factors, which are outside of the Federal Reserve's control, likely explain why real wages have failed to keep pace with productivity growth for at least the past 15 years. For such reasons, we can never be sure what growth rate of nominal wages is consistent with stable consumer price inflation, and this uncertainty limits the usefulness of wage trends as an indicator of the Fed's progress in achieving its inflation objective."

    One could read this in either direction. We could get excessive(?) wage growth without the commensurate pick up in inflation. Or they could raise rates as inflation picks up with out wage growth.

    I see it as more likely that wage growth picks up first as we've seen below-target inflation for many years and haven't seen accelerating inflation since the 1970s when unions were powerful enough to negotiate price hikes into future contracts (Most Violent Years!) That's no longer the case.

    I think the Fed is more optimistic than the bond markets because they see Europe recovering which will raise the equilibrium rate and bring down the American trade deficit. But this doesn't mean Yellen will choke off wage growth. In fact she suggested running tight labor markets can make the economy more productive in the long run:

    "A tight labor market may also work to reverse some of the adverse supply-side developments resulting from the financial crisis. The deep recession and slow recovery likely have held back investment in physical and human capital, restrained the rate of new business formation, prompted discouraged workers to leave the labor force, and eroded the skills of the long-term unemployed.15 Some of these effects might be reversed in a tight labor market, yielding long-term benefits associated with a more productive economy. That said, the quantitative importance of these supply-side mechanisms are difficult to establish, and the relevant research on this point is quite limited."

    Sorry for the wall of text.

    ReplyDelete
  7. Oh and finally on the "bourgeois virtues" and "A Most Violent Year" I liked this quote from DeLong's link to Keynes on the euthanasia of the rentier:

    "There are valuable human activities which require the motive of money-making and the environment of private wealth-ownership for their full fruition. Moreover, dangerous human proclivities can be canalised into comparatively harmless channels by the existence of opportunities for money-making and private wealth, which, if they cannot be satisfied in this way, may find their outlet in cruelty, the reckless pursuit of personal power and authority, and other forms of self-aggrandisement. It is better that a man should tyrannise over his bank balance than over his fellow-citizens; and whilst the former is sometimes denounced as being but a means to the latter, sometimes at least it is an alternative. But it is not necessary for the stimulation of these activities and the satisfaction of these proclivities that the game should be played for such high stakes as at present. Much lower stakes will serve the purpose equally well, as soon as the players are accustomed to them...."

    http://www.bradford-delong.com/2015/03/weekend-reading-john-maynard-keynes-on-the-euthanasia-of-the-rentier.html#more

    ReplyDelete
  8. I think you're on to something: http://fistfulofeuros.net/afoe/a-little-model-of-the-labour-market/

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Nice post.

      We have the same idea about the big picture of procyclical shifts in labor productivity as workers switch between firms and industries. I might frame it a bit differently than you do, though. I'm more inclined to see the problem in terms of coordination broadly, rather than matching, so I'm doubtful that an optimal career path is a useful benchmark. It seems to me that even when an economy is at "full employment," there is a very large fraction of the workforce that could be doing something more productive if demand were greater -- and (and this is important) if the coordination problems involved in shifting people to new jobs could be overcome. I don't think the reason mature capitalist economies grow no faster than 2-3% a year is that this is the limit to potential output in any physical sense, but because the pace of reallocation of labor and other resources if growth were faster would require more active planning by the state (or by a centralized financial system.) Along with this, while I agree that the lower productivity growth we see in periods of slack demand probably reflects in some part poor matches between workers and employers, and also the erosion of "human capital" associated with unemployment, I think it also, and probably more importantly, reflects the fact that at any given moment the economy includes a mix of more and less productive enterprises, and labor moves to the former from the latter more rapidly when demand is strong.

      Anyway, it's an area I'd like to think about more. If you get any interesting responses to your post, do let me know.

      Delete
    2. What's the short identifier for the ECEC data series? I can't find it in FRED?

      Delete
    3. You have to gett it from the BLS -- not everything is in FRED! http://www.bls.gov/ncs/ect/

      There are three distinct series that you will need to splice together.

      Delete
    4. Bad news: http://fistfulofeuros.net/afoe/testing-the-snakes-and-ladders-model/

      ECI is more strongly correlated with the output gap than ECEC, not less.

      Delete
    5. It all depends what period you look at. The Great Recession is unusual in that wages deccelerated across the board, which is not typical of previous downturns. If you try 1986-2008, you'll find a stronger correlation with ECEC and the output gap, and no correlation between ECI and the output gap at all. This is also consistent with the idea (from Leijonhufvud among others) that wage flexibility trends to amplify rather than dampen employment fluctuations, because in the short run there is very little substitution between labor and other factors, while income effects are strong.

      Delete
  9. Brilliant post, as always.

    A note on the "realness" of wages:

    There is (at least) one component of labor compensation that IS a basket of consumption goods rather than a nominal wage: employer-sponsored health insurance. I've thought a bit about what could be learned from exploiting the fact that compensation has a real (in kind) component and a nominal (wage) component, but I've never been able to pin it down exactly.

    ReplyDelete
  10. Great post, but you have to stick to this rather than those tests... I'm disappointed that no one figured out what the blip was in 1994/5 -- this is the EITC reform under Clinton that dramatically expanded the subsidy for low wage workers. This of course spiked supply and effective pay while lowering costs for employers.

    ReplyDelete
  11. Companies can increase wages for a number of reasons. The most common reason for raising wages is an increase to the minimum wage.
    Thanks for sharing with us
    php training in kerala

    ReplyDelete
  12. This is really an interesting post to read and as a mobile app development company, we agree with most of the views of the author.

    ReplyDelete
  13. Thank you for the information you provide, it helped me a lot! it's great
    php internship in kochi

    ReplyDelete
  14. Well-cleared Explanation shared from this blog about Causes and Effects of Wage Growth
    mobile app development company toronto

    ReplyDelete
  15. Thanks for the post, it's really helpful
    php course in kochi

    ReplyDelete
  16. Thank you for the information you provide, it helped me a lot! it's great

    php course in kochi

    ReplyDelete
  17. I really enjoyed reading this blog. It was explained and structured with perfection; Best Digital Marketing Company in Delhi

    ReplyDelete
  18. I’ll bookmark your site and take the feeds also? I’m happy to search out a
    lot of helpful information here within the publish, we’d like develop more
    techniques on this regard, thank you for sharing.


    It company in kochi

    ReplyDelete
  19. Thank you for bringing to a halt my long search topic.
    python internship in Kochi

    ReplyDelete
  20. Handy details. Fortunate us I stumbled upon your web site unintentionally, and i'm amazed precisely why this specific accident didn't was held previous! I personally book marked the item.

    software development company in kerala

    ReplyDelete
  21. Hey there
    Thanks for sharing this informative article, Keep on updating more like this

    Try - Zinzo - Online Grocery Shopping app to get groceries at lowest prices

    ReplyDelete
  22. Excellent Blog! I would like to thank for the efforts you have made in writing this post. vinilos decorativos

    ReplyDelete
  23. Thanks for sharing this precious information this help me in my project

    ReplyDelete
  24. ดูหนัง Best movie online websites Click Now

    ReplyDelete
  25. 1688 Betting on online is the best answer for the gambler.

    ReplyDelete
  26. 619คาสิโน Easy to earn money just by clicking the link

    ReplyDelete
  27. 1688 The number 1 best website to make Money.

    ReplyDelete
  28. maria The number 1 best website to make Money.

    ReplyDelete
  29. 168 website online the best in the worlds.

    ReplyDelete
  30. เว็บหวยสามารถ Online lottery website that gives full price best price in Thailand need this website only.

    ReplyDelete
  31. เว็บสล็อต สำหรับผู้ที่เริ่มสนใจใน เกมสล็อต ที่มีผู้เล่นส่วนใหญ่การันตีว่าสนุกและคุ้มสุดๆ เพียงแค่คุณมองหาเว็บสล็อตแตกง่ายแล้วเข้าสมัครสมาชิก พร้อมเลือกเกมที่ถูกใจหรือเหมาะสมกับความสามารถของตัวเองมากที่สุด จากนั้นให้เริ่มศึกษาเทคนิคเพื่อการเกมสล็อตที่ทำเงินได้จริงดังต่อไปนี้ รับรองว่าคุณจะได้ผลลัพธ์เป็นเงินกำไรที่ชัดเจนอย่างแน่นอน!

    ReplyDelete
  32. สูตรบาคาร่า sa gaming Welcome everyone, good service, easy to use. Fun games make a lot of money. one website complete

    ReplyDelete
  33. this site can help you find a lot of moneyslt

    ReplyDelete
  34. This comment has been removed by the author.

    ReplyDelete
  35. wm casino website online the best in the world

    ReplyDelete
  36. I appreciate your effort and want you to keep on posting such posts.
    App development companies in Kochi

    ReplyDelete
  37. I am so grateful for your blog.Thanks Again
    Python internship in Kochi

    ReplyDelete
  38. I am so grateful for your blog. Thanks Again
    Php training in Kochi

    ReplyDelete
  39. pk789 สล็อต เว็บสมาชิกใหม่สล็อตออนไลน์บาคาร่าออนไลน์คาสิโนมาแรง ยอดเยี่ยมความอัศจรรย์เกมคาสิโนบาคาร่าออนไลน์ที่น่าเฝ้าดู pg slot เว็บไซต์ที่เก็บเกมสล็อตหรือบาคาร่าออนไลน์

    ReplyDelete
  40. Pgkub365 เครดิตฟรี อะไรเป็นสิ่งที่คุณจำเป็นต้องไตร่ตรองเมื่อเข้าเล่นสล็อต ? อัตราการเข้าเล่นสล็อตเป็นมิเตอร์ที่สำคัญสำหรับผู้เล่นสล็อต PG SLOT บทความนี้พยายามที่จะให้ความกระจ่างเกี่ยว

    ReplyDelete
  41. Really appreciate you sharing this article. Much thanks again.

    ReplyDelete
  42. It was definitely informative. Your site is useful.

    ReplyDelete
  43. Everything is very open with a really clear explanation of the challenges.

    ReplyDelete
  44. Hi, happy that i saw on this in google. Thanks!

    ReplyDelete
  45. You put truly extremely accommodating data. Keep it up.

    ReplyDelete
  46. thank you for sharing such a great bog it is very helpful.

    ReplyDelete
  47. This blog posts are more interesting and impressive.

    ReplyDelete
  48. Really satisfied with all the information I have found in this article.

    ReplyDelete
  49. Excellent post. I was checking constantly this blog and I am impressed.

    ReplyDelete
  50. pg autoslot เป็นหนึ่งในเกมสล็อตออนไลน์ที่ได้รับความนิยมจากผู้เล่นในวงกว้าง เป็นผลิตภัณฑ์ของ PG บริษัทพัฒนาเกมแห่งเอเชียที่มีชื่อเสียงในวงการสล็อตออนไลน์ ด้วยความคมชัดและฟีเจอร์ที่น่าสนใจ

    ReplyDelete
  51. This post resonated with me deeply. Thank you for your honesty
    ipl365 casino
    ipl 365 casino

    ReplyDelete

  52. Keep posting like these informative articles.

    ReplyDelete

  53. thanks for sharing great blog article thanks again

    ReplyDelete

  54. Valuable info. Fortunate me I discovered your website by chance

    ReplyDelete

  55. I did a Google search about the topic and found most people will believe your blog

    ReplyDelete

  56. Perfect just what I was looking for!

    ReplyDelete

  57. Really a great addition. I have read this marvelous post

    ReplyDelete

  58. Nice blog, I will keep visiting this blog very often

    ReplyDelete